Listing 1 - 3 of 3 |
Sort by
|
Choose an application
Honesty in voting, it turns out, is not always the best policy. Indeed, in the early 1970s, Allan Gibbard and Mark Satterthwaite, building on the seminal work of Nobel laureate Kenneth Arrow, proved that with three or more alternatives there is no reasonable voting system that is non-manipulable; voters will always have an opportunity to benefit by submitting a disingenuous ballot. The ensuing decades produced a number of theorems of striking mathematical naturality that dealt with the manipulability of voting systems. This 2005 book presents many of these results from the last quarter of the twentieth century, especially the contributions of economists and philosophers, from a mathematical point of view, with many new proofs. The presentation is almost completely self-contained, and requires no prerequisites except a willingness to follow rigorous mathematical arguments. Mathematics students, as well as mathematicians, political scientists, economists and philosophers will learn why it is impossible to devise a completely unmanipulable voting system.
Microeconomics --- Voting --- Social choice --- Political science --- Game theory. --- Mathematical models. --- Games, Theory of --- Theory of games --- Mathematical models --- Mathematics --- Polls --- Elections --- Politics, Practical --- Suffrage --- Balloting --- Voting - Mathematical models. --- Social choice - Mathematical models. --- Political science - Mathematical models.
Choose an application
Voters today often desert a preferred candidate for a more viable second choice to avoid wasting their vote. Likewise, parties to a dispute often find themselves unable to agree on a fair division of contested goods. In Mathematics and Democracy, Steven Brams, a leading authority in the use of mathematics to design decision-making processes, shows how social-choice and game theory could make political and social institutions more democratic. Using mathematical analysis, he develops rigorous new procedures that enable voters to better express themselves and that allow disputants to divide goods more fairly. One of the procedures that Brams proposes is "approval voting," which allows voters to vote for as many candidates as they like or consider acceptable. There is no ranking, and the candidate with the most votes wins. The voter no longer has to consider whether a vote for a preferred but less popular candidate might be wasted. In the same vein, Brams puts forward new, more equitable procedures for resolving disputes over divisible and indivisible goods.
Elections - Mathematical models. --- Elections -- Mathematical models. --- Finance, Public - Mathematical models. --- Finance, Public -- Mathematical models. --- Voting - Mathematical models. --- Voting -- Mathematical models. --- Voting --- Elections --- Finance, Public --- Government - General --- Political Institutions & Public Administration - General --- Law, Politics & Government --- Mathematical models --- Electoral politics --- Franchise --- Polls --- Mathematical models. --- Politics, Practical --- Social choice --- Suffrage --- Political science --- Plebiscite --- Political campaigns --- Representative government and representation --- JSTOR-DDA --- Public finance --- Multi-User. --- E-books --- Balloting
Choose an application
The likelihood of observing Condorcet's Paradox is known to be very low for elections with a small number of candidates if voters’ preferences on candidates reflect any significant degree of a number of different measures of mutual coherence. This reinforces the intuitive notion that strange election outcomes should become less likely as voters’ preferences become more mutually coherent. Similar analysis is used here to indicate that this notion is valid for most, but not all, other voting paradoxes. This study also focuses on the Condorcet Criterion, which states that the pairwise majority rule winner should be chosen as the election winner, if one exists. Representations for the Condorcet Efficiency of the most common voting rules are obtained here as a function of various measures of the degree of mutual coherence of voters’ preferences. An analysis of the Condorcet Efficiency representations that are obtained yields strong support for using Borda Rule.
Voting --- Mathematical models. --- Condorcet, Jean-Antoine-Nicolas de Caritat, --- Political science. --- Political economy. --- Game theory. --- Economic theory. --- Public finance. --- Economics. --- Economic Theory/Quantitative Economics/Mathematical Methods. --- Political Economy. --- Public Economics. --- Political Science. --- Game Theory, Economics, Social and Behav. Sciences. --- Polls --- Elections --- Politics, Practical --- Social choice --- Suffrage --- Caritat, Jean-Antoine-Nicolas de, --- Condorcet, Antoine-Nicolas Caritat de, --- Condorcet, C.-F., --- Condorcet, Marie Jean Antoine Nicolas, --- Condorcet, --- De Caritat, Jean-Antoine-Nicolas, --- Kondorsė, Zhan Antuan, --- Mathematics. --- International Political Economy. --- Math --- Science --- Administration --- Civil government --- Commonwealth, The --- Government --- Political theory --- Political thought --- Politics --- Science, Political --- Social sciences --- State, The --- Cameralistics --- Public finance --- Currency question --- Economic theory --- Political economy --- Economic man --- Public finances --- Games, Theory of --- Theory of games --- Mathematical models --- Mathematics --- de Caritat, Jean-Antoine-Nicolas, --- Condorcet --- Condorcet, Jean-Antoine-Nicolas de Caritat --- de Condorcet, Marie Jean Antoine Nicolas de Caritat --- de Condorcet, Nicolas --- Schwartz, Joachim, --- Game theory --- Voting - Mathematical models --- Paradoxes --- Condorcet, Jean-Antoine-Nicolas de Caritat, - marquis de, - 1743-1794
Listing 1 - 3 of 3 |
Sort by
|